第30章 《佃農理論》英語原著 (24)

[1].UndertheauspicesoftheUniversityofNanking,Buckdirectedaforty-manteaminthepilationoffarmingdatainChinaduring1929-36.Theoriginaldata,whichappeartohavepassedunnoticed,areavailableinJ.L.Buck,ed.,LandUtilizationinChina-Statistics-AStudyof16,786Farmsin168Localitiesand38,256FarmFamiliesinTwenty-twoProvincesinChina,1929-1933(Nanking:UniversityofNanking,1937).Duringthepreparationofthisimpressivevolume,BuckwrotethenotedChineseFarmEconomy(1930),andLandUtilizationinChina(1937),bothofwhichhavebeendistributedbyTheUniversityofChicagoPress.However,Buck'searlierworksarealsoimportant:AnEconomicandSocialSurveyof102FarmsnearWuhu,Anhwei,China(Nanking,1923);AnEconomicandSocialSurveyof150Farms,YehshanCounty,Hopei,China(Nanking,1926);andFarmOwnershipandTenancyinChina(Shanghai:NationalChristianCouncil,1927).

Surveysbyindependentwritersaside,otherorganizationswhichhavecon-ductedsurveysincludetheDepartmentofInternalAffairs,theRealEstateBureau,theNationalGovernmentStatisticsDepartment,theExecutiveYuan,andtheLegislativeYuan.Ihavefoundtheseindependentfindingsgenerallyconsistentwithoneanother.

[2].Thiscanbeconvenientlydemonstratedinfigure3,chapter2.Condition(a)isobtainedbyraisingq/h,andcondition(b)byloweringf/h.Ineithercase,ahighervalueof(q-f)hisdefined,resultinginahigherrentalpercentage.Notethattheseimplicationsapplytofixedandsharerentsalike.

[3].Buck,ChineseFarmEconomy,p.148.Nofurtherinformationisprovided.

[4].ChineseNationalGovernment,ShengchingRouteEconomicReport(1931),p.102.

[5].SeeLegislativeYuan,StatisticalMonthly(1930),2,5;andDepartmentofInternalAffairs,PublicReportsofInternalAffairs(1932),2,1;5,1and2.

[6].Seetable4inchapter8ofthisstudy.InJapan,therentalsharerestrictionenactedin1946wasamaximumof25percentoftheyieldforpaddy,and15percentforuplandfields,reflectingarecognitionofthehigherrentalshareforpaddyfieldsunderfreemarketconditions.SeeMinistryofAgricultureandForestry,AgriculturalLandReformLegislation(Tokyo,1949).

[7].Buck,ChineseFarmEconomy,p.149.Therentalsharesprovidedareaveragesofsamplefarmsineachlocality(elevenlocalitiesinChina,1921-25),andthe66.6percentcitedispurelyincidental.Seetable2inibid.,p.148.

[8].TheseaveragesareputedfromChen,LandRentsofVariousProvincesinChina(Shanghai:CommercialPress,1936),pp.102-3.

[9].Theseconditionscanlikewisebedemonstratedbymovingtheq/handflhcurvesinfigure3,chapter2accordingly.

[10].AndrewJ.Grajdanzev,ModernKorea(NewYork:InstituteofPacificRelations,1944).Theaveragefarmsizesareputedfromdataintable2,p.291;andthelandpricesareseenintable5,p.292.

[11].SeeBuck,LandUtilizationinChina,table23,p.197.Withminordifferencesinmagnitude,identicalpatternsareseenintables7and8,pp.272-73.Notealsothatinibid.,p.197,ownerfarms(average4.22acres)arelargerthantenantfarms(average3.56acres).Thisisbecausetenancyoccursmorefrequentlyonpaddyfieldsthanondrylandeverywhere.SeeSidneyKlein,ThePatternofLandReforminEastAsiaafterWorldWarII(NewYork:BookmanAssociates,1958),p.229ff.SeealsoBuck,Statistics,chap.2,tables23and26;andchap.7.

[12].Buck,ChineseFarmEconomy,pp.156-57.Apparentlyfailingtoseethattherentalpercentageisavariabletoinsureefficientfarming,Buckproceededtodiscussaprogramof"fair"rent.

[13].Ibid.Buck'sfindingisfromasampleof2,542farmsinfifteenlocalities,sevenprovinces,China.Theslightlyhigheryieldsperacreintenantfarmsareperhapsduetoahigherproportionofpaddyfieldsundertenancy,whichBuckdidnotdiscern.Forsimilarevidence,seeBuck,FarmOwnershipandTenancyinChina.

[14].Bray,"FarmTenancyandProductivityinAgriculture:TheCaseoftheUnitedStates,"FoodResearchInstituteStudies(1963),p.25.AlthoughBrayprovidednoformaltheoryofsharetenancy,thetraditionalargumentdidnotpasshisintuition:

Theresource-efficiencyargumentissomewhatacademic……Bothtenantandlandlordhaveanincentivetotrytoincreasethemarginalproductivityoftheirownresources……neitherwhollysucceeds……Forexample,alandlord'ssuggestionthatathirdcultivationofthecornwouldpay(atnocosttohim)maybemetwiththetenant'ssuggestionthatthelivingroomreallywouldbeimprovedbynewwall-paper(atnocosttohim)[ibid.,p.27].

ThelackofsignificantdifferenceinresourceuseamongdifferentleasesisalsonoticedbyWalterG.Miller,WalterE.Chryst,andHowardW.Ottoson,"RelativeEfficienciesofFarmTenureClassesinIntrafirmResourceAllocation,"ResearchBulletin461(IowaAgriculturalandHomeEconomicsExperimentStation,November,1958),pp.321-37.EvidencefromtheUnitedStates,however,isnotheavilyusedinthisstudy.Thisisbecausevariousgovernmentfarmpolicieswhichresultindifferentconstraintsonpetitionmighthaveaffectedresourceuseunderdifferentcontractsindifferentways.

[15].TheseaveragesareputedfromdatainAndrewJ.Grajdanzev,"StatisticsofJapaneseAgriculture,"mimeographed(NewYork:InstituteofPacificRelations,1941),table17,p.32.Thefindingsarebasedonaboutninety-fivesamplefarmsineachcategory.Thesamepatternisobservedif"able-bodiedman-units"areusedinsteadof"numberofmembersperfamily."ForevidencefromTaiwan,seechapter7ofthisstudy.